Could QALYs Help in Assessing High-Priced Cancer Treatments?
Other nations use ‘quality-adjusted life-years’ to measure the cost-effectiveness of drugs, but this tool has been anathema in the United States — so far
For doctors at Memorial Sloan-Kettering Cancer Center in late 2012, it was an easy call. The drug Zaltrap, new on the market (Bach 2012) for treatment of patients with metastatic colorectal cancer, promised to provide an overall survival benefit of 1.4 months compared with a standard chemotherapy regimen. But so did Avastin (bevacizumab) — and the two drugs had similar mechanisms of action, preventing the interaction of VEGF with its receptors. The chief difference was that Zaltrap, initially priced at $11,000 for one month of treatment, cost more than twice as much as Avastin. So the oncologists decided not to use this costly drug. And from the perspective of the cancer center, the story has a happy ending: The marketers of Zaltrap began offering the drug to hospitals at a 50% discount.
But other comparisons of oncology products are not so straightforward. A new drug may offer a modest improvement in overall survival quality of life in the absence of a survival benefit. What then?
Outside the United States, policymakers turn to a measurement unit called the “quality-adjusted life-year,” (see “What’s a QALY?”), though with less enthusiasm than in years past to inform decisions on allocating resources to new drugs. And some experts think it may be time for QALY’s American debut.
To quantify value
In an essay in the New York Times, some prominent oncologists and cancer researchers set forth their prescription for improving cancer care (Emanuel 2013). By way of introduction, they said the FDA had approved 13 anticancer agents in 2012, each costing more than $5,900 per month — and that only one offered a survival benefit exceeding six months. The heart of the essay was a set of five recommendations (see box below). Although the word wasn’t used, the thorny issue of value was implicit in each recommendation. Consumers commonly regard high price as an indication of high value whether they’re purchasing wine, automobiles, higher education or, alas, health care goods and services.
Perhaps that shouldn’t be terribly surprising because, as the health economist Tina Shih, PhD, points out, we really don’t know how to quantify value. Shih is an associate professor of medicine at the University of Chicago and director of its Program in the Economics of Cancer.
Health economists have various tools for evaluating interventions (Table 1), the simplest of which, in theory, is cost-minimization analysis. If two different therapies produce the same outcome, you just choose the less expensive one. Such was the call made by the Memorial Sloan-Kettering doctors at the time that Zaltrap was introduced. Combining length of life and quality of life in a single metric, the QALY enables comparisons of interventions in disparate diseases. In the U.K., the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) mandates use of cost-utility analysis as a tool — but not the sole tool — to determine which interventions should be provided by the National Health Service. It’s a strike against a new intervention if its cost per QALY exceeds £30,000, the upper limit of NICE’s arbitrary range for cost-effectiveness. Shih says QALYs are best employed from a societal perspective, and not for making treatment decisions for individuals with a disease, especially in end-of-life situations.
Table 1 Analyses used in health economics research | |||
---|---|---|---|
Analysis | Use | Metric | Caveats |
Cost of illness | Measuring the economic burden of a disease | Costs from perspective of interested party or parties (e.g., society, third-party payer, business, government) | Defining the illness may be complicated Inclusion of indirect costs generates controversy |
Cost-benefit | Computing total costs and benefits of an intervention | $ gained or lost from the intervention | Difficult to quantify some components |
Cost-effectiveness | Comparing the costs & benefits of interventions not expected to produce the same outcomes | $ per natural unit (e.g., life-years gained, duration of disease-free survival, response rate, mm Hg in BP reduction) | Unit of comparison may not be the most clinically relevant measure |
Cost-minimization | Comparing interventions expected to produce the same outcome (e.g., generic simvastatin vs. branded Zocor) | Price differential | Not easy in most cases to demonstrate clinical equivalence Limited practical use |
Cost-consequence | Comparing alternative interventions by computing the components of their incremental costs and consequences | List of each component | Doesn’t generate an aggregated result |
Cost-utility | Comparing disparate interventions employed in disparate diseases, for purpose of resource allocation | Incremental $ per QALY compared with alternative intervention | QALYs in different diseases may not be commensurate |
Is end of life different?
Even NICE now makes exceptions for end-of-life treatments, largely in reaction to the furor that erupted in 2008 when it rejected some new cancer drugs because they weren’t deemed sufficiently cost-effective. The next year, NICE made major adjustments (http://bit.ly/nice-EOL), allowing drugs used in end-of-life care to exceed the threshold if the treatment is aimed at a small patient population and extends life by at least three months, compared with the current treatment, in patients whose life expectancy is less than 24 months.
None of the 2012 approvals represents a dramatic breakthrough, such as a new first-line treatment that adds years to cancer patients’ lives. Instead, they’re for patients already in dire straits — patients with metastatic disease for which second- or third-line treatments no longer are effective. Some of these drugs wouldn’t pass muster with NICE because they serve small populations and don’t extend life by at least three months.
What oncologists think
Even so, a recent survey of U.S. and Canadian oncologists suggests that the majority of oncologists wouldn’t balk at high prices for such drugs (Ubel 2012). When asked what treatment cost per life-year gained represented “good value for money,” about 70% selected an incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) of $100,000 or less. But when oncologists were randomly presented with hypothetical new drugs for metastatic cancer that cost either $50,000 or $125,000 more than standard chemotherapy costing $25,000, the median increase in life expectancy stipulated by oncologists to justify using the $75,000 drug was six months, which translates into $100,000 per life-year gained. The median survival benefit oncologists selected to support use of the more-expensive drug also was six months, but in this case the cost per life-year gained was $250,000.
Figure 1 Relationship between quality and quantity of life
Which intervention would you choose? Compared with Usual Care, Intervention A offers shorter length of life but improved quality of life. Intervention B provides higher quality of life than Usual Care but the same length of life; the triangle bounded by the sloping and vertical red lines and the sloping black line represents the incremental gain in quality afforded by Intervention B. Compared with Usual Care, the incremental gain in quality from Intervention B is less than that provided by Intervention A, however. Intervention C provides longer length of life than Usual Care or Intervention A or B but lower quality of life than those interventions or Usual Care. Intervention D initially offers actual improvement in quality of life followed by a steep decline, and although length of life is longer than with any other intervention or Usual Care the quality of life ultimately is greatly diminished.
Each is the best-case scenario for cost per QALY, because if the time is spent in less than perfect health, the cost per QALY would be even higher.
Although the study shows that oncologists seem to be rather inconsistent and illogical in their approach to the value of their drugs, the authors said their results shouldn’t be taken as criticism of oncologists, for several reasons:
- Oncologists aren’t trained to use cost-effectiveness data in decision-making.
- Oncologists aren’t comfortable using such data.
- Oncologists usually aren’t aware of the cost of the drugs they’re prescribing (other studies show they are concerned about the amount of a patient’s copayment, which in itself can adversely affect compliance with therapy).
- Oncologists are taught to just let policymakers deal with these matters.
In another study, oncologists at Massachusetts General Hospital and the Dana-Farber Cancer Institute were asked to identify the minimum survival benefit they’d need to prescribe a hypothetical new treatment for metastatic lung cancer if the new treatment cost $70,000 per year more than the standard-of-care treatment and if there was no difference in quality of life between the standard and the new treatment (Nadler 2006). The responses ranged from one day (ICER of $25.6 million) to one year or more (ICER of $70,000), with the median and mean responses being $280,000 and $319,000 respectively (Figure 2).
Figure 2 Gain in life expectancy needed to justify use of hypothetical drug costing $70,000 per year more than standard care; incremental cost-effectiveness ratios
Frequency of response
The dollar amount above each column shows the implied incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) for each response, as provided by academic oncologists in Boston when asked to attach an outcome to a dollar amount ($70,000 more per year than standard care). The median ICER was $280,000 and the mean ICER, which excluded the “1 day” response, was $319,000. (A study of the preferences of patients with metastatic cancer suggests that they are willing to pay comparable amounts per year of life gained [Seabury 2012].) When asked to attach a dollar amount to an outcome, however, 70% of U.S. oncologists responding to a national survey indicated $100,000 or less per life-year gained was a reasonable definition of “good value for money” or cost-effectiveness (Neumann 2010a). In a survey of U.S. and Canadian oncologists, when asked what treatment cost per life-year gained represented “good value for money,” about 70% of the physicians selected an ICER of $100,000 or less, but when the question was framed differently, many were satisfied with much higher ICERs (Ubel 2012).
SOURCE: Nadler 2006
Suspicion
In the United States, QALYs often are regarded with suspicion, so much so that the Affordable Care Act forbids the Patient-Centered Outcomes Research Institute to use the cost per QALY “or similar measure that discounts the value of a life because of an individual’s disability as a threshold to establish what type of health care is cost effective or recommended.”
The Affordable Care Act forbids consideration of cost effectiveness in studies funded by the Patient-Centered Outcomes Research Institute, but most oncologists would like to have that information, according to a study by Peter Neumann, ScD, PhD, a Tufts University professor.
Peter Neumann, ScD, professor of medicine at Tufts University School of Medicine and director of Tufts’ Center for the Evaluation of Value and Risk in Health, speculates that the ambiguous language of this passage might permit ICERs using cost per QALY to be calculated but not compared with a threshold, but that it might also be construed as a broader ban on cost-utility analysis (Neumann 2010b). (Neumann has studied QALYs extensively and published numerous scholarly articles about their use in oncology among other areas.)
The fact that legislators saw fit to insert language in the Affordable Care Act to ban the use of QALYs may seem unfortunate and bizarre in a nation where there’s so much talk about the high costs of health care. Whatever the reasoning behind the legislation, it runs counter to what most oncologists apparently want. In a national survey of U.S. oncologists, 80% “strongly or somewhat agreed” that more use of cost-effectiveness data is needed in coverage and payment decisions for cancer drugs, and that more government research is needed on the comparative effectiveness of cancer drugs (Neumann 2010a). Well, good luck with that.
But while the oncologists said they’d like to see the government provide more comparative effectiveness research, only 21% thought government should determine whether a drug provides good value — and a mere 6% thought insurance companies should do so. Instead, they wanted value determinations to be made by physicians (60%), not-for-profit organizations, (57%) and patients (37%). Taken together, these studies suggest that if oncologists want to make value-based treatment decisions, at least some of them need guidance in evaluating cost-effectiveness data.
“QALYs are easy to criticize, but it’s hard to capture anything with a single number,” Neumann says. He cites the Dow Jones Industrial Average and the measurement of snowfall by inches as common metrics that tell us something interesting but hardly tell us everything needed to adequately assess the phenomena in question.
Likewise, he says, “The QALY has a place as a crude but imperfect measure of value. I recoil when it’s used rigidly.”
From the perspective of pharmaceutical companies, an objection to QALYs is that overreliance on them could stifle innovation. According to this argument, some drugs — especially first-in-class agents — merit a high price and a high cost per QALY in order to spur further research. Herceptin (trastuzumab), for example, was initially approved as first-line therapy for metastatic breast cancer, and for that indication its cost per QALY gained was calculated as at least $125,000. That’s far above the conventional threshold. But in the adjuvant setting, its cost per QALY was found to be only $26,000. Had the drug been rejected initially because of an unacceptably high cost per QALY, the opportunity to study it in the adjuvant setting might never have arisen. But Shih says such pharmacoeconomic analyses should be interpreted cautiously, because they often are just retrospective mathematical models that are subject to manipulation.
Table 3 Common arguments against using QALYs in end-of-life situations | |
---|---|
Argument against QALY | Counterargument |
|
An intervention can enhance life (i.e., generate a gain in QALYs) even if it doesn’t extend life |
|
|
|
Instability of preferences becomes a problem only when patients’ preferences are used, so a practical solution is to use the preferences of the general public |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Source: Round 2012 |
Comparisons are difficult
In the case of Zaltrap, oncologists had no need to call on QALYs to determine that the initial price of the new drug was far too high. Its value relative to a competing product was immediately apparent because the efficacy and safety of each drug were regarded as equivalent, and market forces (lack of demand) soon led to a downward adjustment in price.
Comparisons of other cancer drugs tend to be far more difficult because the products aren’t equivalent, in which case QALYs may be one tool that complements others to help policymakers, physicians, and patients determine which drug offers the best value.
People like the freedom to use whatever drug they want, says Shih, but at some point we have to face the reality that resources are limited. If we don’t want to use cost-effectiveness analyses to allocate resources, what process are we going to use, she asks, other than the random process employed right now?
Neumann says that to reject QALYs in the absence of a better metric is to implicitly argue that we’re better off if the trade-offs revealed by QALYs remain hidden. Still, in the current environment, one person’s quest for value may be perceived and portrayed by someone else as the imposition of rationing.
For further reading
Bach PB, Saltz LB, Wittes RE. In cancer care, cost matters. New York Times. October 14, 2012.
Emanuel EJ. A plan to fix cancer care. New York Times. March 23, 2013.
Nadler E, Eckert B, Neumann PJ. Do oncologists believe new cancer drugs offer good value? Oncologist. 2006;11(2):90–95.
Neumann PJ. What next for QALYs? JAMA. 2011;305(17):1806–1807.
Neumann PJ, Greenberg D. Is the United States ready for QALYs? Health Aff (Millwood). 2009;28(5):1366–1371.
Neumann PJ, Palmer JA, Nadler E, Fang C, Ubel P. Cancer therapy costs influence treatment: a national survey of oncologists. Health Aff (Millwood). 2010a;29(1):196–202.
Neumann PJ, Weinstein MC. Legislating against use of cost-effectiveness information. N Engl J Med. 2010b;363(16):1495–1497.
Round J. Is a QALY still a QALY at the end of life? J Health Econ. 2012;31(3):521–527.
Seabury SA, Goldman DP, Maclean JR, Penrod JR, Lakdawalla DN. Patients value metastatic cancer therapy more highly than is typically shown through traditional estimates. Health Aff (Millwood). 2012;31(4):691–699.
Ubel PA, Berry SR, Nadler E, Bell CM, Kozminski MA, Palmer JA, Evans WK, Strevel EL, Neumann PJ. In a survey, marked inconsistency in how oncologists judged value of high-cost cancer drugs in relation to gains in survival. Health Aff (Millwood). 2012;31(4):709–717.
Woodward RM, Menzin J, Neumann PJ. Quality-adjusted life years in cancer: pros, cons, and alternatives. Eur J Cancer Care (Engl). 2013;22(1):12–19.
More like this
- Determining the Cost-Effectiveness of a Computer-Based Smoking Cessation Intervention in Primary Care
- Pursuing a Bang for the Buck In the Battle of the Bulge
- Plans Help Bridge Cost Discussion
- Ups and Downs at ASCO 2014
- How Rebates, Copayments, and Administration Costs Affect the Cost-effectiveness of Osteoporosis Therapies
Our other journal
P&T Journal for November 2014
FEATURES
LETTER TO THE EDITOR
Medications for Parkinson’s Disease
PERSPECTIVE
The Changing Roles of P&T Committees
Epilepsy Management: Newer Agents, Unmet Needs, and Future Treatment Strategies
PIPELINE PLUS
Modest Growth Seen in Epilepsy Market
MEETING HIGHLIGHTS
European Society of Cardiology and Transcatheter Cardiovascular Therapeutics
BOOK REVIEW
“Generic: The Unbranding of Modern Medicine,” by Jeremy A. Greene, MD, PhD
DEPARTMENTSMEDICATION ERRORS
Misadministration of IV Insulin Associated With Dose Measurement And Hyperkalemia Treatment
PRESCRIPTION: WASHINGTON
FDA’s Proposed 503B Draft Compounding Guidance Raises Concerns of All Kinds
New Drugs/Drug News
Pharmaceutical Approval Update
DRUG FORECAST
Riociguat (Adempas): a Novel Agent For the Treatment of Pulmonary Arterial Hypertension and Chronic Thromboembolic Pulmonary Hypertension

Paul Lendner ist ein praktizierender Experte im Bereich Gesundheit, Medizin und Fitness. Er schreibt bereits seit über 5 Jahren für das Managed Care Mag. Mit seinen Artikeln, die einen einzigartigen Expertenstatus nachweisen, liefert er unseren Lesern nicht nur Mehrwert, sondern auch Hilfestellung bei ihren Problemen.